Game Theory & Soccer ⚽
Intro
As we have seen throughout the semester, game
theory can be applied to a variety of applications. Let’s see how we can apply it to the game of
soccer, focusing on penalty kicks. What
strategies should a striker
use when taking a penalty kick and what can a goalkeeper do
to prevent the ball from going in the net?
Let’s find out! So grab your cleats
and a ball, and let’s play some soccer!!
When is there a
penalty kick? If player 1 gets fouled
inside the opposing player 2’s penalty box then player 1 will get a penalty
kick. Before we “dive” in, let’s first
explain what a penalty kick is.
- The ball is placed
on the penalty mark in front of the goal (12 yards away).
- The striker has a single kick and tries to put the ball in the net while the
goalie tries to stop it.
It only takes 0.3
seconds for the ball to hit the back of the net so the goalie doesn’t have
enough time to intercept the ball.
Instead, he must choose a side to dive toward or guess where the striker will shoot and hope it’s the same side.
Figure 1: Penalty kick
For our purposes, we’ll
assume the following:
1. To make things
interesting, we’ll say the goalie is a guy and the striker is a girl. This obviously isn’t true in a real game
(unless you play co-ed pick-up ;p) but it makes it easier to distinguish who we
are talking about.
2. The goalie dives
either left or right (we’ll use the striker’s
perspective throughout).
3. The striker shoots left or right. The shooter won’t ever kick it in the center to the goalie…that’s a big no no. We won’t worry about the case where she kicks
the ball in the air or on the ground either.
4. If the striker kicks the ball to the same side the goalie dives, we’ll assume the
shot is blocked. If the striker kicks the ball to the opposite side the goalie dives, we’ll assume
it went in the net and is a goal.
Pure or Mixed
Strategy?
cThis setup is similar to the game of matching pennies. In matching pennies, you
and an opponent simultaneously reveal a penny.
If both pennies show heads, your opponent pays you $1. If one penny is heads and the other is tails
then you pay your opponent $1. In this
case, you can be viewed as the goalie while your opponent is the striker in our soccer example.
Figure 2: Payoff matrices for matching pennies and penalty kicks
Figure 2 shows simplified
payoff matrices for matching pennies and penalty kicks. As we can see, this is a zero-sum game
because each of the four instances in the matrix adds up to 0. It turns out that there aren’t going to be
any pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Why? I’ll go over this in my presentation and we’ll
look at each instance to answer this question.
Feel free to comment on why that might be!
We learned from Nevin’s
presentation on Nash’s Theorem that there must be at least one Nash Equilibrium
for all finite games. Since there is no
pure strategy Nash equilibrium then one must exist for mixed strategies which
involve a probability distribution over two or more pure strategies. This means that the players will randomly
choose among their two choices (left or right).
So, what should the players do? What might be an optimal strategy? It turns out that both players should pick a side with equal probability. This means the striker kicks left ½ the time and right ½ the time and the goalie dives left ½ the time and right ½ the time. Why is this an optimal strategy? It is because the players are less likely to figure out what their opponent will choose. It allows the players to be less predictable.
Figure 3: Payoff
matrix with probability 50%
This is, in fact, an example of a Nash equilibrium
because both players can’t gain by changing their strategy. If the striker
has a 50/50 chance of shooting the ball
either to the left or right then it doesn’t matter which way the goalie dives because he will have an equal chance of stopping
the ball. Similarly, if the goalie is diving left or right with equal 50% probability then it
doesn’t matter which side the striker chooses to shoot the ball because she will have a 50%
chance of scoring. By randomizing your
options, you become less predictable to your opponent.
This is easier to see if we look at other strategies that
are not optimal where probabilities are different throughout. If the striker kicked left 100% of the time then
it would be easy for the goalie
to stop the shot
because he would then dive left 100% of the time. This is also true if the striker shoots left 99% or 98% and so forth.
The goalie will always want to go to the left.
Conclusion
In actuality, both players have a choice of more
than two tactics (going left or right). The shooter might aim low or high. She might shoot to the left, right or center. She might also go for either power or accuracy
(if you didn’t already know, it is very easy to boot the ball with too much
power or aim too high which forces the ball to go waaay over the net. Not good my friends!). The optimal strategy for both players will be
mixed but it is best that players keep their probabilities of choosing left or
right as close to 50% as possible.
We will see that game theory can be applied to
many other sports including baseball and tennis. Can you think of any other strategic
interactions that are found in other sports?
Sources
Harford, Tim. "World Cup Game Theory." What
economics tells us about penalty kicks. June 24, 2006. Accessed April 12, 2017.
http://www.slate.com/articles/arts/the_undercover_economist/2006/06/world_cup_game_theory.html.
Spaniel, William. Game Theory 101: Soccer Penalty Kicks.
June 16, 2010. Accessed April 12, 2017. https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=OTs5JX6Tut4.
Spaniel, William. "The Game Theory of Soccer Penalty
Kicks." The Game Theory of Soccer Penalty Kicks. June 12, 2014. Accessed
April 12, 2017.
https://williamspaniel.com/2014/06/12/the-game-theory-of-soccer-penalty-kicks/.
Is the reason that there is no pure strategy Nash Equilibrium because there is no dominant strategy? Meaning that if the striker decides to always kick the ball left, the goalie can just change his strategy to dive left.
ReplyDeleteI think that's part of it. It also seems to me that there's no Nash Equilibrium, because if one of the players knows what the other is doing, they'll change their strategy. In other words, there isn't one strategy (left or right) that always works best for one of the players.
DeleteYou are both right!
DeleteDid you happen come across any of the probability distributions for top soccer players in the world and their history of penalty kicks in your research? There are some pretty nutty soccer fans out there who follow the sport with incredible detail.
ReplyDeleteI didn't but I did find some stats on penalty kick percentage for some professional teams. It turns out that the overall penalty kick percentage for making the goal (for 5 different teams in 2010) was just under 77%.
Deletehttp://www.arcticicehockey.com/2010/7/9/1560962/soccer-penalty-kick-percentage
I think it's interesting how in soccer some players will take a riskier shot to avoid leaving the result up to chance. For instance I remember how Landon Donovan would aim for the very corner of the net because even if the goalie knew where he was shooting, he wouldn't be able to save it. I feel like this strategy is a little more risky because the chances of missing the goal completely might be higher than having your shot blocked with the standard guessing strategy, but I respect how some players let the game be decided by skill rather than chance.
ReplyDeleteSometimes players do kick the ball right in the middle, assuming the goalie is going to anticipate a shot to either the left or the right (making the goalie look kinda stupid). Factoring this in to your blog, would we just be adding an extra section to those matrices you put up? If so, this would be really interesting because there is still no dominant strategy.
ReplyDelete